In my assigned role as the (anti) Thomas Robert Bannister (Malthus), I thought I would return to the blog after a far-too-long hiatus with this post to share recent work. Note that this work is the other main area of research beyond my dissertation interest of the role of energy revolutions in economic history. I'll return to that one given recent posts here, but for now:
This work asks many questions, the fundamental one being do we really need to radically change behaviours to attain zero growth, or, what do we really mean by zero growth?
The conditional answer is that our world can achieve zero total growth (in the expected lifetimes of some of us) while still having per-capita GDP growth. The key, wearing my anti-Malthus hat, is population-conditional. To introduce the topic, here is a figure from my model that shows GDP levels peak at about 2080. I think that is a very radical outcome, with many implications. It is based on several forecasts, including the current UN low population forecast.
The only other forecast I'll mention for now is that the per-capita real GDP increases through the forecast period. The second-largest caveat is the large forecast error bands; I'll simply note that at least I show them. Most climate models (of which this is a member) eschew error estimates. I can do so because I use empirical forecasting methods.
So, peak GDP levels in 2080 with continuing real per-capita output growth (forever). A surprising result certainly to me. The largest caveat in this method is the population curve you believe we are on. I'll discuss that in a future post. For now, just enjoy that a (credible?) model exists that allows the zero-gowth crowd and the lift-the-poor crowd to coexist on the same model path.
I will monitor questions. This will be my EEA talk; just a heads-up for those who wish to stockpile (potatoes and other) ammunition.
Saturday, November 30, 2013
Lars P. Syll On How to Get Away With Scientific Fraud With Economics Textbooks
By Lars P. Syll
As is well-known, Keynes used to criticize the more traditional economics for making the fallacy of composition, which basically consists of the false belief that the whole is nothing but the sum of its parts. Keynes argued that in the society and in the economy this was not the case, and that a fortiori an adequate analysis of society and economy couldn’t proceed by just adding up the acts and decisions of individuals. The whole is more than a sum of parts. This fact shows up already when orthodox – neoclassical – economics tries to argue for the existence of The Law of Demand – when the price of a commodity falls, the demand for it will increase – on the aggregate. Although it may be said that one succeeds in establishing The Law for single individuals it soon turned out – in the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu theorem firmly established already in 1976 – that it wasn’t possible to extend The Law of Demand to apply on the market level, unless one made ridiculously unrealistic assumptions such as individuals all having homothetic preferences – which actually implies that all individuals have identical preferences.Read rest here.
This could only be conceivable if there was in essence only one actor – the (in)famous representative actor. So, yes, it was possible to generalize The Law of Demand – as long as we assumed that on the aggregate level there was only one commodity and one actor. What generalization! Does this sound reasonable? Of course not. This is pure nonsense!
Marie Duggan on Steven Kates and the role of History of Economic Thought
Marie has reviewed Kates' recent book on the role of history of economic thought in what he correctly sees as a crisis in the profession. She tells us:
Steven Kates warns us that if the history of economic thought (HET) leaves the field of economics, economics will lose a good bit of its theoretical heart (p. 27). He makes this argument against two opposing straw men. The first is those who define an economist as someone who can apply sophisticated econometric techniques to data. The other is the view among HET practitioners that since HET has been shunted aside within economics by mathematics, the wise make allies with historians. He views this latter as dangerous to economics as a discipline: “The core issue is whether the subject area of the history of economic thought adds to the study of economics. The question is not whether there are a thousand other uses of HET” (p. 67).
This book acts as a wake-up call that practitioners in HET may have an honorable role to play in reversing the decline of theory in our profession. That’s a big task, and Kates certainly has the fighting spirit.
Read the whole review here.
Friday, November 29, 2013
More on The Sociology of Development - Reposted by Hampton Institute
Crooks, Liars, Idiots, and Plutocrats: Again on the effects of the Debt Ceiling Limit
A modified and updated version of the previous post has been published in the last number of Dollars & Sense Magazine here. The main addition is a discussion of the 'solution' to the last crisis, and a very brief discussion of the brewing storm for early next year.
The Default Prevention Act of 2013, included in the continuing resolution, reinstated government funding at pre-shutdown levels through January 15, 2014, and authorized suspension of the debt limit through February 7, 2014, at which point we would be basically in the same situation we were in October. Under the agreement reached to end the shutdown and to avoid breaching the debt-ceiling limit, the House of Representatives and the Senate agreed to hold negotiations to reach an accord by December 13 on a plan for fiscal policy for the next ten years.Note all of this is functional and is being used to maintain austerity policies in the US.
This is not very different from the previous debt-ceiling crisis in 2011, when the so-called “Super Committee” was charged with finding $1.5 trillion in savings over a ten-year period, but eventually failed to reach an agreement. That triggered, in early 2013, the infamous “sequestration,” cuts of discretionary spending totaling around $1.2 trillion over the same period. Note that, as for the Super Committee and the previous Bowles-Simpson National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform, the terms of any accord by the members of the Budget Panel led by Senator Patty Murray (D-WA) and Representative Paul Ryan (R-WI) (who were members of the Super Committee) would imply further “fiscal adjustment.” The main disagreements are that Democrats would like to see targeted spending cuts, and to increase revenue by closing tax loopholes for corporations and wealthy individuals, while Republicans would not want any tax increases, and demand cuts to entitlement spending. The attempt at bipartisanship did not go all that well last time, and chances are that it will fail again.
Thursday, November 28, 2013
Paul Davidson and the good old days for workers
Letter from Paul published in The Economist edition of November 2nd.
* SIR – “Labour pains” (November 2nd) pointed out that the share of wages in national income has fallen after being nearly constant for decades after the second world war. During the post-war decades the middle class prospered because of the full-employment policies started by Franklin Roosevelt and continued by both Democratic and Republican presidents and Conservative and Labour governments in Britain.You can see this letter and others here.
In this period the growth of union power, enshrined in legislation and policies, pursued the sharing of monopoly rents and profits of corporations with their workers. By the 1970s, however, the seeds were sown for the beginning of the end of middle-class prosperity. The anti-union policies of Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher made it socially and politically popular to see unions as the villains in the economy. This was quickly supplemented by firms outsourcing to foreign countries where an hour’s worth of labour was paid a much lower real wage.
But now, a new threat is growing that will further hollow out the middle class and make even more significant differences in the distribution between the top 1-2% and the rest of society. This threat is automation. You correctly indicate that policymakers should think about broadening capital ownership as a way of boosting income to workers and restoring a prosperous middle class.
For a creative approach to restoring middle-class prosperity, I recommend the work of Professor Robert Ashford in the forthcoming issue of the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics called “Beyond Austerity and Stimulus: Democratising Capital Acquisition With the Earnings of Capital As a Means of Sustainable Growth”. Professor Ashford proposes a capital-ownership broadening policy that big companies adopt to produce enhanced earnings for their employees, customers, and other poor and middle class people; enhanced corporate profit and growth; reduced need for welfare dependence; and enhanced sovereign creditworthiness.
Paul Davidson
Editor
Journal of Post Keynesian Economics
Boynton, Florida
Lars P. Syll: Krugman dismisses heterodox economics students
By Lars P. Syll
Paul Krugman today rides out — like his brother in arms, Simon Wren-Lewis — to defend mainstream economics. According to Krugman, yours truly and others of that ilk are wrong in blaming mainstream economics for not being relevant and not being able to foresee the crisis. To Krugman there is nothing wrong with “standard theory” and “economics textbooks.” If only policy makers and economists stick to “standard economic analysis” everything would be just fine. I’ll be dipped! If there’s anything the last five years have shown us, it is that economists have gone astray in their shed of tools. Krugman’s “standard theory” — neoclassical economics – has contributed to causing todays’s economic crisis rather than to solving it. [...] So now all you young economics students that want to see a real change in economics and the way it’s taught — now you know where you have Krugman & Co. If you really want something other than the same old neoclassical catechism, if you really don’t want to be force-fed with neoclassical mumbo jumbo, you have to look elsewhere.Read the rest here.
The deep causes of the Great Divergence: or why China fell behind
In the last post, I suggested that Kenneth Chase's explanation of why China invented, but did not pursue the development of gunpowder and guns to its ultimate consequences, could be seen as the very deep cause of the so-called Big Divergence, i.e. of the rise to dominance by Western Europe. Chase explains the lack of interest in the development of firearms in China as the result of geographical conditions and how they affected warfare. He argues that two types of warfare developed after the invention of firearms.
In a sense, this is a more sophisticated geographical argument than the one put forward by Jared Diamond in Guns, Germs and Steel, since it is capable of explaining why Western Europe and not China (or India, or the Ottomans) dominated the world, while Diamond (in a book that uses old political economy arguments, in particular the notion of surplus, something typical of many historians as argued here before) can only explain why Europeans conquered the people outside Eurasia (that had less luck in the choice of animals and plants to domesticate, and less chance to spread them in an East-West axis with similar climate) really. Note that Cipolla long ago had noted that the main advantage of Westerners when they arrived in the East (Vasco da Gama in 1498) was basically military.
The only thing missing in most of these non-economists discussions of the causes of Western European dominance is the role of demand expansion in technological progress and economic growth in general. But many historians do have an implicit demand-led growth or Keynesian story too, I should add. By the way, on the Keynesian view of many historians it might be worthwhile reading the last section of Garegnani and Palumbo's entry on the Elgar Companion to Classical Economics available here.
PS: This also suggests that on some level, particularly military and naval technology, the West was already ahead of the Oriental Empires considerably before Pomeranz and the revisionists time frame (i.e. around 1800). However, the argument does not hinge on Eurocentric views about the superiority of culture, as in many neo-Weberian arguments (e.g. David Landes).
"Where there were technologically advanced agrarianate societies that were not threatened by steppe or desert nomads, we find the combination of firearms and pikemen, with an emphasis upon infantry (western Europe, Japan). Where there were technologically advanced agrarianate societies that were threatened by steppe or desert nomads, we find the combination of firearms and wagons, with an emphasis upon cavalry (eastern Europe, the Middle East, India, north China)."From a geographical point of view Chase divides Eurasia in three regions. The Arid Zone, which includes those areas that supported pastoral nomads, the Inner Zone including the areas that were directly threatened by pastoral nomads, principally eastern Europe, the Middle East, India, and China, and the Outer Zone that was not directly threatened by pastoral nomads, principally Western Europe and Japan, as shown in his map below.
In a sense, this is a more sophisticated geographical argument than the one put forward by Jared Diamond in Guns, Germs and Steel, since it is capable of explaining why Western Europe and not China (or India, or the Ottomans) dominated the world, while Diamond (in a book that uses old political economy arguments, in particular the notion of surplus, something typical of many historians as argued here before) can only explain why Europeans conquered the people outside Eurasia (that had less luck in the choice of animals and plants to domesticate, and less chance to spread them in an East-West axis with similar climate) really. Note that Cipolla long ago had noted that the main advantage of Westerners when they arrived in the East (Vasco da Gama in 1498) was basically military.
The only thing missing in most of these non-economists discussions of the causes of Western European dominance is the role of demand expansion in technological progress and economic growth in general. But many historians do have an implicit demand-led growth or Keynesian story too, I should add. By the way, on the Keynesian view of many historians it might be worthwhile reading the last section of Garegnani and Palumbo's entry on the Elgar Companion to Classical Economics available here.
PS: This also suggests that on some level, particularly military and naval technology, the West was already ahead of the Oriental Empires considerably before Pomeranz and the revisionists time frame (i.e. around 1800). However, the argument does not hinge on Eurocentric views about the superiority of culture, as in many neo-Weberian arguments (e.g. David Landes).
Wednesday, November 27, 2013
The Fiscal-Military State and Western Hegemony
An often neglected, at least in economics, argument for the rise of the West (leaving the debate of when the Big Divergence took place, if around 1800 or before, for another post), is its fiscal advantage when compared to the Oriental Empires (Mughal, Ottoman, Safavid and Qing). Patrick O'Brien, the prominent author of the idea of Western fiscal exceptionalism, suggests that the smaller and more urbanized polities of the West found it easier to tax their populations than the Eastern empires with more extensive territories, larger populations and less urbanized economies, even if the latter were in many respects more advanced than the former. The figure below shows that to some extent the Dutch dominance, and then the English ascension, go hand in hand with and increase of tax revenue as a share of GDP.
The figure shows only the Ottoman empire, at the bottom of the graph, as a comparison to the Western economies, but it gives a sense of the stark differences after the mid-17th century. In a sense, O'Brien's argument can be seen as a variation of Charles Tilly's famous argument that "War made the State, and the State made war." Inter-State wars gave a military edge to Europe, which was solidified in the higher revenues which led to larger and more organized navies in particular. In this respect, the work by Jan Glete on the effects of a permanent navy on State formation deserves also careful reading.
However, the reasons for the militaristic nature of the Western economies is not well developed in the Fiscal-Military State literature. Kenneth Chase's book on the history of firearms provides an interesting answer.
He argues that early firearms were not very effective when
used against cavalry because of their overall lack of
mobility, poor rates of fire, and limited accuracy. As a result, their
effectiveness was restricted to infantry and siege warfare, and were not
used in regions threatened by nomads (which include all the Oriental
Empires), in which cavalry warfare was dominant. That is why the Chinese invented guns, but failed to keep up with Western developments. The same could be said about sailing techniques, and the combination of guns and sails, to use the terms of Cipolla's classic book.
Tuesday, November 26, 2013
Dean and Cole vs. Crafts on the Industrial Revolution
My understanding of the debate on how fast, or revolutionary if you prefer (Rondo Cameron suggested it shouldn't be called a Revolution), was the Industrial Revolution is that a lot hinges on how much weight one puts on the cotton sector, in which most of the increase in productivity and growth took place in the early stages. Dean and Cole (review here) presented the traditional notion of a relatively fast growing economy, while Crafts and Harley argued for a gradualist transformation in which only a few sectors grew fast (cotton, iron and transportation) and the transformations were slow at best. The graph below by Wrigley shows nicely the difference in both views.
Note that Wrigley assumes that the estimates for GNP and GNP per head for the early 1830s are accurate, hence the differences in rates of growth imply diverse initial levels. Wrigley does not challenge the consensus view that is increasingly dominated by Crafts and Harley's numbers, but the graph below, also from his book, provides surprising evidence for a very large expansion of income.
Note that energy consumption per capita in England increases at a very fast pace all through the 18th century. It is well known that, particularly in periods of transformation of the structure of production, energy consumption per capita is closely correlated with income growth.
PS: Total factor productivity (TFP) is the measure used by Crafts and others to conclude that productivity was slow to grow in the period. On the problems with TFP go here.
Note that Wrigley assumes that the estimates for GNP and GNP per head for the early 1830s are accurate, hence the differences in rates of growth imply diverse initial levels. Wrigley does not challenge the consensus view that is increasingly dominated by Crafts and Harley's numbers, but the graph below, also from his book, provides surprising evidence for a very large expansion of income.
Note that energy consumption per capita in England increases at a very fast pace all through the 18th century. It is well known that, particularly in periods of transformation of the structure of production, energy consumption per capita is closely correlated with income growth.
PS: Total factor productivity (TFP) is the measure used by Crafts and others to conclude that productivity was slow to grow in the period. On the problems with TFP go here.
Saturday, November 23, 2013
More on The Sociology of Development: Towards A Re-articulation of Dependency Theory
The sociology of development as a field of study, a
structure of knowledge, providing an interpretive grid through which to render
impoverished regions of the world intelligible has its roots after the
completion of Second World War with the crystallization of ‘Modernization
theory', which constituted an ideation that societies are understood to move
from social positions of tradition to modernity polar ends of an evolutionary
continuum. At some point, incremental changes give way to a qualitative jump
into modernity, marked by the essence of industrialism. In this sense, the
Third world is perceived to be below the threshold of modernity, with a
preponderance of traditional-like features such as an extended kinship social
structure and, due to the lack of progress towards political differentiations,
similar to that of Western forms of democratization, strict hierarchical
sources of authority, altogether negating the possibilities to move beyond
disintegrated autarkic primary economic activities (Parsons, 1964).
The development of a high extent of differentiation: the development of free resources which are not committed to any fixed, ascriptive groups; the development of wide non-traditional, “national,” or even super-national group identifications; and the concomitant development, in all major institutional spheres, of specialized roles and of special wider regulative or allocative mechanisms and organization, such as market mechanisms in economic life, voting and party activities in politics, and diverse bureaucratic organizations and mechanisms in most institutional spheres (Eisenstadt (1973: 23).
According to Rostow (1960), all societies can be placed
along a linear continuum from undeveloped to developed along a ‘stages of
economic growth’ path, derived from an extensive study of Western economic
development. In ‘traditional society’, the first stage, it is deemed that
economic output is limited because of inaccessibility to innovative technology.
At the second stage, ‘the preconditions for take-off, modern science,
attributed to “Western Europe of the late seventeenth and early eighteenth
centuries” (Rostow, 1960, p. 6) ensues new innovations in production in
agriculture and industry, fostering widespread education, entrepreneurship, and
institutions capable of mobilizing industrial capital; capitalistic investments
increase, especially in transport, communication and raw materials.
Nevertheless, despite the development of some modern manufacturing, traditional
social structures and production techniques remain:
In many cases, for example, the traditional society persisted side by side with modern economic activities, conducted for limited economic purposes by a colonial or quasi-colonial power (Rostow, 1960, p.7)
Rostow’s third stage is ‘the Take-off’, in which traditional
barriers to economic growth, like the effect of a dual economy, are overcome.
At this point, capital investment increases rapidly and new industries expand
exponentially, as does an ‘entrepreneurial class’—economic growth becomes a
normal condition” (Rostow, 1960, p. 36). At the fourth stage, ‘the Drive to
Maturity’, technology becomes more complex and what produced is now less a
matter of economic necessity, and more a question of consumer choice. This
leads to the final fifth stage of high consumption, in which economic sectors
specialize in the manufacturing of highly sought after consumer durables and
basic life needs are mutually satisfied. In a play on Marx, Rostow’s analysis
suggests that the West, which “is more developed industrially only shows, to
the less developed, the image of its own future’ (Marx, 1954, p. 19). The assumption is that capitalism is a historically progressive system, which is transmitted from the privileged economically advanced countries to the rest of the world by a continual process of
destruction and replacement of pre-capitalist social structures (Palma, 1978).
The problem with modernization theory is that it is quite ahistorical, with respect to the global capitalist exploitation.
'Modernization’ theory can, and has been, be interpreted as a ‘blame the
victim’ approach to problems affecting the ‘Third World’. Rostow ignores the
external influences like colonialism that contributed to social in the Third
World. Rostow’s, and for most of ‘modernization’ theory, the unit of analysis
is the nation-state of the ‘Third World’, emphasizing internal dynamics, sectors
and sub-sectors, combined with the causal role of technology. As such,
conclusions drawn from this approach are that all nations, regardless of the
history of imperialism, colonialism, etc., should be able to modernize with
emulation of more developed economies and their diffusing of highly advanced
technology.
Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy, in Monopoly Capital (1960),
building on the path-breaking work of Michel Kalecki and Joseph Steindl, assess
the degree to which monopoly, as measured by the market concentration ratio of
large capitalist firms (corporations) in economically advanced countries,
ensues an inverse of Marx’s famous hypothesis that the ‘laws of motion’ of
capitalist development in produces a ‘tendency for the surplus to fall. Rather,
the economic surplus, defined as the gap, at any given level of economic
activity—effective demand in Keynesian terminology—, between what is produced
and the socially necessary costs of producing it, under monopoly capitalism has
a tendency to rise (Baran & Sweezy,1966, pp. 9, 52-57).
Since aggregate levels of effective demand for total output
determine the level of economic activity, crises of capital accumulation are
inevitable if the monopoly sector cannot sustain its power via sufficient
investment opportunities to absorb its accumulating share of the total surplus
produced. Rather than let this insufficiency put downward pressures on
potential profits as a whole, various stabilizing factors are set in motion,
which include classical Keynesian government deficit spending, research &
development (although risky without reliable forecasts potential spillover
effects), waste (as evidenced by a sales effort, i.e. consumerism), or
imperialism—the last of which provides the foundations for the dependency theoretical
approach to economic development.
In this sense, for an understanding of the fundamental
division between economically advanced countries and impoverished ones, it is
requisite to place attention to the extent to which foreign investment acts as
an outlet for investment-seeking surplus generation. Unlike Lenin’s theory of
imperialism, foreign investment is a method of extracting wealth, not a channel
through which surplus is directed, ensuing underdevelopment (Baran &
Sweezy, pp. 104-105). Underdevelopment is a thus process by which monopoly
capital in economically advanced nations exploit economically weaker countries
by exporting capital to the extent that profits produced (from the production
of cheaper consumer goods or raw materials via lower wages in these countries,
for example) are repatriated. It is the process by which the expropriation of
“foreign sources of supply and foreign markets, ena[ble] [the agents of]
monopoly capital to buy and sell on specially privileged terms” (Baran &
Sweezy 1966, p. 201), ensuring, caeteris paribus, their positions of power in
the world are sustained. The result is that economically weaker countries
suffer the retardation of the requisite forces to spawn autonomous and dynamic
process of self-governance of the conditions that constitute independent
social/political/economic coordination, planning and control.
The argument is that (Baran & Sweezy, pp. 9,178-179)
monopoly capitalism is tantamount to the degree to which large capitalist firms
in economically advanced countries have as their counterpart the “exploitation
of much of the rest of the world” and, as a result, constitute international
relations as a “hierarchical system with one or more leading metropolises,
completely dependent colonies [even if not name, certainly in practice] at the
bottom, and many degrees of superordinate and subordination in between […]
[t]hese features are of crucial importance to the functioning of both the
system as a whole and its individual components […] (Baran & Sweezy, 1966,
pp. 178-179). As such, “we cannot hope to formulate adequate development theory
and policy for the majority of the world’s population who suffer from
[impoverishment] without first learning how their past economic and social
history gave rise to their present underdevelopment” (Frank, [1966] 1969).
Underdevelopment is neither an original nor traditional social position. Hence,
it cannot be assumed that the contemporary position of the Third World can be
understood as solely a reflections of its internal historically specific
social, political, economic, and organizational characteristics. The process by
which monopoly capital in economic advanced countries extract surplus from
less-developed countries through capital exports limits the latter’s ability to
achieve the status of the former. Thus, 'modernization theory' is utterly
unsatisfactory, for such an approach
[…] in all its variations, ignores the historical and structural reality of the underdeveloped countries. This reality is the product of the very same historical process and systemic structure as is the development of the now developed countries’ (Frank 1969, p. 47).
To suggest that social, political, and economic advancement
of the underdeveloped world can be generated by the diffusion of what is deemed
modernizing institutions, values, etc. is fundamentally erroneous. If
development fails to occur, it is not because within the Third World there are
mere obstacles to diffusion because of innate poverty arising from some form
Gerschenkronian ‘backwardness’, but due to the net outflow of vital resources,
whether natural, monetary, human, technological etc. The implication is that
underdevelopment is not because of the “the survival of archaic institutions”,
or some inability to contract some ‘modern man’ (Inkles, 1969) syndrome; on the
contrary, it is generated by the same capitalist development that led to the
domination by economic advanced countries, that is, “the development of
capitalism itself” (Frank, [1966] 1969). Capitalism, hence, is an operation that cements a peripheral
latifundium system, via the constant forces of ‘primitive-accumulation', what
Myrdal (1957) defined as international ‘backwash’ effects, that reproduces a
cleavage between ‘town and country’, centre and periphery, on a tremendously
enlarged basis (cf. Bukharin & Lenin, 1929).
Viewed from this standpoint, dependency theory is a
manifestation of what David Harvey (1978, 2007) defines as ‘accumulation by
dispossession’ by virtue of which dialectical forces of motion and contradiction
generate vast disparities of wealth and power on a worldwide scale. The world
economy is reproduced as a world-system (Wallerstein, 1979) of ‘unequal
exchange’ (Emmanuel, 1972; Amin 1974, 1976), in which ‘underdevelopment’ ensues
peripheral internal long-run stagnation (Bornschier & Chase-Dunn, 1985, pp.
39-40). The terms of trade for the periphery fall precipitously – this is the
Prebisch-Singer hypothesis (Prebisch 1950). As Samir Amin (1976, p. 292) notes,
“whereas at the center growth means development, making the economy more
integral, in the periphery growth does not mean more development, for it
dis-articulates the economy. Since the imbalance of international trade defines
the mechanisms by which capital is drained from former colonized countries, there
is no way for peripheral countries in the world economy to ‘catch up’ in
Rostowian fashion (p. 383).
Nevertheless, the social facts that constitute the
particular social conditions for the constant negation of a ‘just price’ in
international trade ‘admits of varying interpretation’ (Frank, 1977). Case in
point is the extent to which the periphery is in fact ‘peripheralized’. To
suggest that the capitalist world economy simply, by definition, produces a
centre-periphery polarity (Frank, 1967; Wallerstein, 1974), is to pay
insufficient attention to understanding the extent to which economic
development in the periphery is a convoluted association of varying social
processes, rather than the mere result of a state’s homogenized world-systemic
position (Gellert, 2010).
According to Cardoso and Faletto ([1967] 1970), for
instance, development in the periphery, while controlling for socioeconomic
income differentials, is likely if foreign capital penetration creates
spillover effects. That is, partial economic growth is viable through what Peter Evans (1995) describes as the practice of an ‘embedded autonomy’-an apparent solidified social network between the state and civil society
(which consists of economic elites from the centre) that creates the capacity
for the state, as such, to engage in domestic Keynesian aggregate demand
management. Whether this is manifested is the extent to which a peripheral
country does not suffer the inability to borrow in its own currency, in which a
country, most likely a developing one, supplements its domestic unit account of
fiduciary reserve assets with a foreign currency. This is the exemplification
of a country foregoing its national ‘monetary sovereignty’ (Mundell, 1961).
The essence of national 'monetary sovereignty' is the
cartelist (or chartelist) (Goodhart, 1998) conception that emphasizes state
power to establish a particular unit of account, a national currency, which
allows economic calculations to take place (Ingham, 2004). In this sense, money
is a means for accounting for and settling of financial debts, the most
important of which are tax debts, which, in turn, regulate the level of
aggregate demand, and thus determination of national income through the use of
fiscal policy; it represents a [store of financial value] [...] [of which]
general purchasing power is held [...] (Keynes, 1930, p. 3).
In the United States, for example, and in contrast to James O’Connor ([1973] 2002) and Erik Olin Wright’s (1979) fiscal
sociological model for analyzing the intricacies of public finance, which
narrowly centers on a hypothetical natural limit to fiscal policy (Wright 1979,
p.157), the federal government, through open-market operations, sells
government bonds, Treasury securities, which are either bought or foregone by
the Federal Reserve (Fed). If the Fed commits to a policy of purchasing Treasury
securities, the interest rate by which the Federal government is liable on
Treasury securities held by the Fed is lowered. Symmetrically, if the Fed sells
Treasury securities, the Federal Government’s interest burden, which is paid
through taxes denominated in dollars, is raised. By providing a guarantee for
State debt, the Fed delivers the capability for the federal government to use
fiscal policy to regulate aggregate demand. Thus, the extent to which fiscal
policy is an option is determined by the burden of the federal government's
interest payments on Treasury securities to the Fed (cf. Lerner, 1943; Domar, 1944).
From this perspective, 'underdevelopment', or 'dependency',
is the powerlessness a peripheral country to establish its own unit of account
and thus is forced to variably peg its national currency to a foreign reference
currency. What ensues is the inability to use monetary policy—central bank
purchasing and selling of government bonds denominated in the domestic currency
for purposes of controlling the money supply, and thus the cost of credit—, and
fiscal policy, via deficit spending, for domestic economic needs. Since the
central bank is forced to maintain a certain level reserves of the foreign
reference currency such that the price of the domestic currency, in terms of
the reference currency, does not change, this produces a negative
money-multiplier that sets in motion an inherent deflationary bias, which, if
not counteracted by capital inflows to spur aggregate demand, can lead to
abrupt contraction of the monetary base, stinting any supposed progress towards
economic sustainability (cf. Fields & Vernengo, 2012, 2013).
Thus, if any form of government spending is to be engaged,
an 'underdeveloped' country has to issue bonds that are not denominated in its
own currency. This amounts to the attraction of external commercial loans with
the faith of the country's financial markets by foreign investors used as
collateral. As such, country risk is most likely going to exist. If confidence
is lost in the strength of the country's financial markets, leading to a spread
over bonds like US treasury securities, if the foreign reference currency is
the dollar, for example, interest rates on domestic foreign currency
denominated bonds are likely to rise, making government spending very costly,
which removes any form of domestic capacity to spur public investment as an
effective countercyclical policy in the face of economic downturns. This has
been essentially the case of Argentina before the 2001–2002 crisis, and of the
European periphery since the intensification of the Greek crisis in 2011.
Balance of payments constraints can be quite unsupportable,
spawning self-fulfilling financial collapses. Moreover, they altogether
constitute an ideological mask that normalizes the advance of global
cosmopolitan money-capitalist power to dictate the terms of domestic democratic
politics (Ingham, 2008). As such, the extent to which a country is
'peripheralized', is the degree to which its creditworthiness is essentially
evaluated in terms of the degree to which the state takes steps toward lowering
the social wage for the benefit of multinational corporations from the centre
(or core).
***This is a work in progress and I would like to thank
Matias Vernengo, Brett Clark, & Al Campbell for their assistance.***
- Amin, Samir. 1972. "Underdevelopment and dependence in black Africa: Historical origin." Journal of Peace Research 9(2): 105-119.
- Amin, Samir. 1974. "Accumulation and development: a theoretical model." Review of African Political Economy 1(1): 9-26.
- Amin, Samir. 1976. Unequal Exchange. Brighton, UK: Harvester.
- Baran, Paul and Paul Sweezy. 1966. Monopoly Capital: An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order. New York: Monthly Review Press
- Block, Fred. 1981. “The Fiscal Crisis of the Capitalist State.” Annual Review of Sociology 7:1-27
- Bomschier, Volker, and Christopher K. Chase-Dunn. 1985. Transnational Corporations and Underdevelopment. New York: Praeger
- Bukharin, Nikolaĭ, and Vladimir Il'itx Lenin. 1929. Imperialism and world economy. Vol. 4. New York: International Publishers
- Cameron, Angus. 2008. “Crisis? What Crisis? Displacing the Spatial Imaginary of the Fiscal State.” Geoforum 39: 1145-1154
- Campbell, John L. 1993. “The State and Fiscal Sociology.” Annual Review of Sociology 19: 163-185
- Cardoso, Fernando H., and Enzo Faletto. 1967[1970]. Dependência e desenvolvimento na América Latina. Rio de Janeiro: Zahar.
- Cox, Kevin R. 2004. “Globalization and the Politics of Local and Regional Development: The Question of Convergence.” Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 29: 170-194
- Devine, Joel A. 1983. “Fiscal Policy and Class Income Inequality: The Distributional Consequences of Governmental Revenues and Expenditures in the United States, 1949-1976.” American Sociological Review 48(5): 606-622
- Domar, Evsey D. 1944. "The burden of the debt and the national income." The American Economic Review 34(4): 798-827.
- Dymski, Garry A. 1990. “Money and Credit in Radical Political Economy: A Survey of Contemporary Perspectives.” Review of Radical Political Economics 22(2-3):38-65
- Dymski, Gary A. 2005. “Poverty and Social Discrimination: A Spatial Keynesian Approach.” Pp. 230-250 in Reimagining Growth: Towards a Renewal of Development Theory, edited by Silvana De Paula and Gary A. Dymski. New York: Zed Books.
- Ebner, Alexander. 2006. “Institutions, Entrepreneurship, and the Rational of Government: An Outline of the Schumpeterian Theory of the State.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 59: 497-515.
- Eisenstadt, Shmuel N. 1973. Traditional Patrimonialism and Modern Neopatrimonialism. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications
- Fields, David, and Matías Vernengo. 2012. “Hegemonic Currencies during the Crisis: The Dollar versus the Euro in a Cartelist Perspective.” Review of International Political Economy
- Fields, David, and Matías Vernengo. 2013. "Dollarization." Wiley-Blackwell Online Encyclopedia of Globalization.
- Emmanuel, Arghiri. 1972. Unequal Exchange: An Essay on the Imperialism of Trade. New York: Monthly Review Press
- Evans, Peter. 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
- Flacks, Richard and Gerald Turkel. 1978. “Radical Sociology: The Emergence of Neo-Marxian Perspectives in US Sociology.” Annual Review of Sociology 4: 193-238
- Frank, Andre Gunder. 1966. The development of underdevelopment. Boston: New England Free Press
- Frank, Andre Gunder. 1969 “The Development of Underdevelopment.” Monthly Review
- Frank, André Gunder. 1977. "Long Live trans-ideological enterprise! The Socialist Economies in The Capitalist International Division of Labor." Review (Fernand Braudel Center): 91-140.
- Gellert, Paul K. 2010. "Extractive regimes: toward a better understanding of Indonesian development." Rural Sociology 75(1): 28-57.
- Goodhart, Charles. 1998. “The Two Concepts of Money.” European Journal of Political Economy, 14(3): 407-432
- Harvey, David. 1978. “The Urban Process under Capitalism: A Framework for Analysis.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 2(1-4): 101-131
- Harvey, David. 2007. "Neoliberalism as creative destruction." The Annals of The American Academy of Political and Social Science 610(1): 21-44
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 1984. Capitalism Divided? London: Macmillan.
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 1996a. “Money is a Social Relation.” Review of Social Economy 54(4): 507-529
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 1996b. “Some Recent Changes in the Relationship Between Economics and Sociology.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 20: 243-275
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 1998. “On the Underdevelopment of the ‘Sociology of Money’.” Acta Sociologica 41(10): 3-18
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 1999. “Capitalism, Money, and Banking: A Critique of Recent Historical Sociology.” British Journal of Sociology 50(1): 76-96
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 2000. “Class Inequality and The Social Production of Money.” in Renewing Class Analysis, edited by Rosemary Crompton, Fiona Devine, Mike Savage, and John Scott. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 2003. “Schumpeter and Weber on the Institutions of Capitalism: Solving Swedberg’s ‘Puzzle’.” Journal of Classical Sociology 3: 297-311
- Ingham, Geoffrey. 2004. The Nature of Money. Cambridge UK: Polity Press
- Inkles, Alex. 1969. “Making Men Modern: On the Causes and Consequences of Individual Change in Six Dveloping Countries.” American Journal of Sociology 75(1): 208-224
- Keynes, John Maynard. 1930. A Treatise on Money: Vol. 1. London: Macmillan
- Lerner, Abba P. 1943. “Functional Finance and the Federal Debt.” Social Research 10(1): 38-51
- Marx, Karl. 1954. Capital, Vol. 1. Moscow: Progress Publishers
- Mundell, Robert A. 1961. “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas.” American Economic Review 51(4): 657-665
- Myrdal, Gunnar. 1957. Economic theory and underdeveloped countries. London: Duckworth
- O’Connor, James. 2002. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
- Palma, Gabriel. 1978. “Dependency: a formal theory of underdevelopment or a methodology for the analysis of concrete situations of underdevelopment?” World Development 6(7): 881-924.
- Parsons, Talcott. 1964. “Evolutionary Universals in Society.” American Sociological Review 29(1)3: 339-357
- Prebisch, Raul. 1950. "El Desarrollo Económico de la América Latina y sus principales problemas." Revista de Economía Argentina 48(379-380): 17-24.
- Rostow, Walt Whitman. 1960. The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto. London: Cambridge University Press.
- Smart, Barry. 2012. “Fiscal Crisis and Creative Destruction: Critical Reflections on Schumpeter’s Contemporary Relevance.” Journal of Classical Sociology 12(3-4): 526-543
- Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. The capitalist world-economy. Vol. 2. London: Cambridge University Press.
- Wright, Erik Olin. 1979. Class, crisis and the state. London: Verso
- Vernengo, Matias. 2006."Technology, finance, and dependency: Latin American radical political economy in retrospect." Review of Radical Political Economics 38(4): 551-568.
Friday, November 22, 2013
Lars Syll on Loanable Funds Theory
By Lars Syll
The classical theory of the rate of interest [the loanable funds theory] seems to suppose that, if the demand curve for capital shifts or if the curve relating the rate of interest to the amounts saved out of a given income shifts or if both these curves shift, the new rate of interest will be given by the point of intersection of the new positions of the two curves. But this is a nonsense theory. For the assumption that income is constant is inconsistent with the assumption that these two curves can shift independently of one another. If either of them shift, then, in general, income will change; with the result that the whole schematism based on the assumption of a given income breaks down … In truth, the classical theory has not been alive to the relevance of changes in the level of income or to the possibility of the level of income being actually a function of the rate of the investment.Read the rest here.
There are always (at least) two parts in an economic transaction. Savers and investors have different liquidity preferences and face different choices — and their interactions usually only take place intermediated by financial institutions. This, importantly, also means that there is no “direct and immediate” automatic interest mechanism at work in modern monetary economies. What this ultimately boils done to is — iter — that what happens at the microeconomic level — both in and out of equilibrium — is not always compatible with the macroeconomic outcome. The fallacy of composition has many faces — loanable funds is one of them.
Economic History blog dedicates space to the Great Depression
Echoes is an Economic History blog worth visiting. Here Philip Scranton's take on the early phase of the recovery and how FDR and the often forgotten Hugh Johnson wanted a wage-led recovery.
As in earlier economic recoveries, in 1933, U.S. production began increasing more quickly than workers could find jobs. A 50 percent increase in industrial output from March to July generated just 14 percent more factory employment. With orders rising, manufacturers commonly extended current employees’ weekly hours instead of rehiring those who had been laid off.Read thing whole thing here.
Hugh "Iron Pants" Johnson, director of the National Recovery Administration, focused on closing this gap as President Franklin D. Roosevelt's first 100 days in office came to an end in June. The purpose of the National Industrial Recovery Act was simple: "Wages are to be increased and hours of work curtailed in order to distribute more widely the available employment," according to the Economist.
"The Administration has made no secret of its belief that if the slump is to be overcome, employment and wages must rise much faster in the initial stages of the recovery than output and prices."
Central Banking in Historical Perspective
Thursday, November 21, 2013
Academics back students in protests against economics dogma
From The Guardian:
A prominent group of academic economists have backed student protests against neo-classical economics teaching, increasing the pressure on top universities to reform courses that critics argue are dominated by free market theories that ignore the impact of financial crises.
The academics from some of the UK's most prestigious institutions, including Cambridge and Leeds universities, said students were being short-changed by their courses, and they accused higher education funding bodies of being a barrier to reforms.
In a startling attack on the agencies that provide teaching and research grants, they said an "intellectual monoculture" is reinforced by a system of state funding based on journal rankings "that are heavily biased in favour of orthodoxy and against intellectual diversity".Read rest here.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)
Inflation, real wages, and the election results
Almost everybody these days accepts at face value that the result of the election was heavily determined by negative perceptions about Biden...
-
"Where is Everybody?" The blog will continue here for announcements, messages and links to more substantive pieces. But those will...
-
There are Gold Bugs and there are Bitcoin Bugs. They all oppose fiat money (hate the Fed and other monetary authorities) and follow some s...
-
By Sergio Cesaratto (Guest Blogger) “The fact that individual countries no longer have their own currencies and central banks will put n...